THE NATIONAL WATER ACT, 1998 - A PRICING STRATEGY FOR RAW WATER USE CHARGES

 

A STRATEGY DOCUMENT

FINAL DRAFT December 1998

 

Department of Water and Sanitation

PREFACE

We all advocate that measures be put in place that ensure long-term water security in South Africa. The challenge is to achieve this in as fair a way as is practicable. The legal foundation for water pricing has already been provided in the National Water Act, 1998. This document provides a strategy for its implementation.

Water is a limited resource in South Africa. In using it, we have obligations to meet basic human needs; the requirements for basic ecological functioning; the legitimate needs of our neighbouring countries; and the redressing of the extreme imbalances with which water is now allocated. Furthermore, when we talk of "water" in this way, we have to think in terms of water of an appropriate quality.

One of the most difficult aspects of managing these obligations is a water-pricing strategy. There can be no doubting the fact that the pricing of water can make a substantial contribution to the efficiency with which we use water, the equity with which we share water, and the sustainability of our water reserves.

This strategy document therefore is an attempt to find a better way to ensure that the pricing of water contributes to long-term water security. Interested parties are urged to study these draft proposals, and respond in a timely fashion, so as to ensure that we understand your perspectives on what is being proposed.

The measures that we are advocating here are designed to be in the enlightened self-interests of all South Africans. A finely-tuned management of water will have immense developmental benefits, and will be a major factor in establishing the quality-of-life prospects of all South Africans.

Ultimately, too, each of our own quality-of-life prospects is tied up in those of our fellow citizens.

Government’s role has to be fair and equitable in treating all sectoral interests. It is the responsibility of all of us to be efficient in our use of resources. If together we can find a practicable, manageable way in which to allocate tariffs to these ends, we shall all be richer.

 

Professor Kader Asmal, M.P.

Minister of Water and Sanitation


TABLE OF CONTENTS

 

1. Introduction

2. Water Supply and Demand

2.1 Factors Influencing Supply

2.2 Factors Influencing Demand

3. Addressing The Problem

3.1 Supply-side Versus Demand-side Management

4. The Objectives That Shape The New Pricing Strategy

4.1 Social Equity

4.2 Ecological Sustainability

4.3 Financial Sustainability

4.4 Economic Efficiency

5. Implementation of the New Pricing Strategy

5.1 Introduction

5.2 Definitions of Water Use

5.3 Pricing Strategy for Water Use

5.3.1 Funding water resource management

5.3.2 Funding water resource development and use of waterworks

5.3.3 Achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water

5.4 Transparency and Accountability

6. Phasing In The New Approach

6.1 Introduction

6.2 Phasing in the Various Charges

7. Application Of Pricing Strategy To Different Categories Of Water Use / User Sectors

7.1 Discharge of Waste (Section 56(5) of the Act)

7.2 Municipal Sector

7.3 Industrial and Mining Sector

7.4 Irrigation Sector

7.5 Streamflow Reduction Activities

7.6 Non-consumptive Use of Water

7.7 Licensing and Registration Fees

8. Conclusion

9. Glossary Of Terms


1.    Introduction

The broad principles underlying the new approach to the pricing of water use are already reflected in the White Paper on a National Water Policy for South Africa, and in the National Water Act, 1998. This document expands on those broad principles, in a manner consistent with the provisions of the new Act, and provides a framework and detailed proposals for implementing the new pricing strategy for water use.

The new approach is concerned with pricing the use of water from South Africa’s water resources, and not with the pricing of water services. Water services, including the pricing thereof, have been dealt with separately in the Water Services Act, 1997. In other words, the new approach deals with first tier water, i.e. the use of water from the water resource. It does not deal directly with second and third tier water, i.e. water supplied in bulk (often by water boards) and distributed to households (usually via a municipality), except for water supplied by Government water schemes. The new approach deals with all first tier water: state and private schemes, as well as ground and surface water.

2.    Water Supply and Demand

In formulating such a new water pricing strategy, it will be necessary to meet the challenges presented by the existing and growing imbalances which exist between the supply of and demand for water in South Africa. The increasing gap between supply and demand has been confirmed by studies carried out by the Department of Water and Sanitation (DWAF), which indicate that the quantity of remaining surface water resources available to meet South Africa’s needs within the most important water catchments will be adequate only until the year 2030 if the present usage patterns and tariff structures are maintained.

2.1   Factors Influencing Supply

There are a number of factors that influence the supply of water in South Africa. These include the fact that:

much of the country is semi-arid with relatively low rainfall; rainfall patterns are erratic, i.e. not consistent in terms of the parts of the country or the time of year in which it falls; regions of high runoff are often situated away from areas of maximum water demand; the country’s groundwater - which is often the main source of supply of water in rural areas - is limited and often of poor quality.

2.2    Factors Influencing Demand

On the other hand, the demand for water in South Africa is growing. Factors that contribute to this growth are:

the high population growth rate; rapid urbanisation; economic development; demands for higher levels of service (such as in-house water rather than communal standpipes); the need to sustain ecological systems; and the drive to provide accessible, drinkable water for everyone in the country.

In the past, the growing demand for water has been accommodated by increases in supply. New dams and transfer schemes have been built to make these increases possible. However, the most easily accessible water sources will soon all have been fully utilised, and it will be necessary to go ever further afield to find new ones. In the future, unless demand patterns are dramatically altered, it will become necessary to import water from neighbouring countries if they are agreeable, or to resort to the desalinisation of sea water. These new supplies will be expensive, and their rising costs will have to be borne by all water users.

3.    Addressing The Problem

3.1 Supply-side Versus Demand-side Management

There are essentially two ways in which the increasing gap between the demand for and supply of water can be closed. The first involves supply-side management, which simply means continuing to expand supply to meet ever-increasing demand. We have suggested above, however, that this would result in significant increases in the cost of water as less favourable sources further afield have to be developed. These rising costs would ultimately have to fall on all water users.

Before these costs are incurred, it is important to make sure that the water that is already available is used efficiently and not wasted. This is best achieved by introducing demand-side measures to manage our water resources. By encouraging all water sectors to use water more efficiently, demand-side management provides a more sustainable long-term solution to the problem of water scarcity than do supply-side measures, because it takes into account the value of water in relation to its cost of provision, thereby treating it more like a commodity.

It is important to note that the focus on demand-side issues does not imply that important supply-side initiatives, such as catchment management (and dealing with unaccounted-for-water), will be neglected in the new approach to water resources management. The optimal solution to address the problem is to apply integrated water resource management, involving supply-side as well as demand-side measures.

 

4.    The Objectives That Shape The New Pricing Strategy

The following objectives are of equal importance in formulating the new pricing strategy:

Each of these are elaborated upon below. These objectives are incorporated into the implementation of the new pricing strategy, which is discussed in Section 5.

4.1 Social Equity

Apartheid policies distorted the provision of water supply services, so that today more than 12 million people do not have adequate supplies of potable water. Apartheid also generated a biased approach to water resource management, and allocation was never merely an economic matter, but a socio-political one. Government water policy, and in particular the provision of subsidies (including those associated with the provision of irrigation water), resulted in considerable advantages to large, mainly white commercial farmers at the expense of emerging black farmers and smallholders. The pricing strategy for water use charges will achieve social equity by redressing the imbalances of the past, both with respect to adequate access to water supply services and with respect to direct access to first tier water.

4.2 Ecological Sustainability

South Africa is committed to following a path of development that is environmentally sustainable. In the case of water, this requires that the availability and quality of water resources inherited by future generations should be adequate to ensure human well-being and the maintenance of ecosystems. As part of overall water resource management, this means that we need to ensure that our levels of water consumption, use, and pollution, as well as the associated infrastructure to impound, supply, treat and dispose of the water, do not cause either unacceptable or irreversible impacts on the population or ecosystems.

The following principles underlie ecological sustainability in the water pricing strategy:

4.3 Financial Sustainability

The methods that have been used by DWAF to finance major bulk raw (i.e. first tier) water schemes in the past are not financially sustainable for a number of reasons. First, inflation was not taken into account, resulting in a decline in the value of tariffs over time in real terms. Second, no provision was made for refurbishment. And third, no provision was made for asset replacement.

A new financial framework is required to accommodate the water sector’s increased need to be financially autonomous, to attract greater contributions to its development from the private sector, and to be financially accountable and sustainable.

In the new approach to water pricing, it is proposed that the full financial cost of supplying water should be recovered from water users, including the cost of capital. The new approach represents a step towards compliance with Generally Accepted Accounting Practice (GAAP). Full compliance is not possible under existing institutional arrangements in the water sector, but should be seen as a longer-term goal.

4.4 Economic Efficiency

Economics is concerned with the optimum allocation of scarce resources between competing uses. This applies equally to the capital resources used in the development of water infrastructure (i.e. dams, reservoirs, pipelines, etc.), and to natural resources such as water. In theory, meeting the goal of optimum resource allocation requires that goods be priced at their opportunity cost, which is simply the value of goods forgone (including environmental goods and services), when a scarce resource is used for one purpose instead of for its next best alternative use.

This has implications for both the pricing of water infrastructure assets (and hence for the cost of capital) and for the pricing of water resources. The former is discussed in more detail in section 5.3.2, which deals with the funding of water resource development and use of waterworks. The latter is discussed below.

If South Africa’s water resources were abundant, there would be no need to consider attaching a price to the water resource itself. However, the need for water conservation and management of demand in conditions of growing scarcity is an important and increasing focus for water policy.

Ensuring an efficient allocation of the country’s scarce water resources requires that the price of the resource be set to reflect its scarcity value. Failing to price water at its scarcity value can result in two kinds of misallocation of water:

In the context of water scarcity, an argument can be made for the introduction of economic incentives in water-stressed catchments to encourage the conservation of water and its shift from low to higher value use. This can be done administratively or by using market-related mechanisms.

 

5.    Implementation of the New Pricing Strategy

5.1 Introduction

The pricing strategy follows from the four objectives already discussed. It aims to achieve in a coherent manner the efficient and cost-effective allocation of water, equity and fairness in the allocation mechanism, and long term sustainability of the natural environment.

The starting point for the pricing strategy is the catchment. It begins with an estimate of the utilisable water available in a catchment. This will be derived from hydrological models of the rainfall/run-off/storage relationships for the catchment. From this amount three claims on water will be deducted.

The three claims are as follows:

Water for meeting basic human needs should thus be considered as a system cost, and will therefore be borne by all the economic users of the system. It is important to note that the subsidisation of the resource cost of 1st tier water (as it travels through to the 3rd tier) should not be considered as a subsidisation of the operation and maintenance costs of the 3rd tier provider of potable water supplies. Third tier costs must be borne in full by the 3rd tier provider of potable water supplies.

Therefore, even if DWAF makes the first tranche of 1st tier water available free of charge to the 3rd tier water supplier, it does not imply that such water will be free to the consumer. It is however intended that the DWAF will, through the proposed regulations in terms of the Water Services Act, require local government to set the basic water supply at the lowest amount possible.

The water that is available once these claims have been met can be allocated within and across catchments (i.e. inter-basin transfers) between competing water users. This water will be classified as economic use of water and is subject to pricing.

 

5.2    Descriptions of Water Use

Section 56 of the National Water Act instructs the Minister to establish a Pricing Strategy for charges for any water use described in Section 21:

(a) taking water from a water resource;

(b) storing water (i.e the water lost due to evaporation of such stored water);

(c) impeding or diverting the flow in a watercourse;

(d) engaging in a stream flow reduction activity (i.e. land-based activities which significantly reduce streamflow);

(e) engaging in a controlled activity (i.e. activities having a detrimental impact on water resources);

(f) discharging waste or water containing waste into a water resource;

(g) disposing of waste in a manner which may detrimentally impact on a water resource;

(h) disposing of water which contains waste from any industrial or power generation process;

(i) altering the bed, banks, course or characteristics of a watercourse;

(j) removing, discharging or disposing of water found underground;

(k) using water for recreational purposes;

It is important to note that the long term objective of the Department of Water and Sanitation is to systematically consider each of the 11 water uses defined above and to decide if and how each one should be priced and charged for. It is acknowledged, however, that it is not feasible to consider developing a pricing strategy for all water uses in a short period of time. For example, while the management of diffuse sources of water pollution and the development of a comprehensive waste disposal charge system are likely to be important components of a future pricing strategy, they cannot realistically be fully implemented in this "first round" of pricing strategy initiatives. The pricing strategy must therefore be seen as a process that evolves over time; it begins by prioritising those uses of water that are likely to generate the most significant and long-lasting impact on South Africa’s scarce water resources.

The intention is to include the establishment of charges only for those water uses which can be expressed in volumetric terms regarding annual quantities abstracted, stored or reducing streamflow in the initial pricing strategy. This relates to the uses specified in section 21 in the following way:

 

5.3 Pricing Strategy for Water Use

In terms of the Act, the Minister may, with the concurrence of the Minister of Finance, from time to time by notice in the Gazette, establish a pricing strategy for charges for any water use (S 56 (1)). This pricing strategy may contain a strategy for setting water use charges-

Each of these are discussed in more detail below. The pricing strategy can only be applied to catchments or schemes where annual water use has been registered or licensed. In the process of registration an assessment will be made of the average annual volumetric use of all water users in accordance with regulations to be promulgated. The database of registered annual volumetric use, as well as the estimated growing demands of water users supplied from Government waterworks, will form the basis on which unit sectoral charges will be calculated for each catchment or scheme. The end user sectors for which unit sectoral charges for 1st tier water will be calculated and announced annually on a catchment basis are the following:

5.3.1 Funding water resource management

Resource management expenditure relates to those activities that are required to regulate, manage and maintain the water resource or catchment. These costs differ from overheads in that they are not related to water sold from individual schemes but are rather the costs related to the management of all water within a water management area as defined in terms of the national water resource strategy (Chapter 2, Part 1 of the Act). These can include the costs of the following functions to be performed by the Department and/or water management institutions exercising delegated or assigned powers under the National Water Act:

Initially, water resource management will continue to be the task of the Department of Water and Sanitation. However, the National Water Act clearly states that the intention is to create Catchment Management Agencies (CMAs) in a staged and progressive manner and to delegate or assign significant water resource management functions to these bodies. The activities of the CMAs will be funded from the water resource management charges, which may be made by and are payable to the relevant CMA. In water management areas where not all catchment management functions have been delegated to CMAs, the relevant CMA will collect charges, and funds due to the DWAF will be passed on to the Department.

To deal with the determination of charges for water resource management, the DWAF’s budget has been restructured to contain an Integrated Catchment Management Trading Account providing for the allocation of Departmental costs and collection of revenue with regard to the following main activities, under which headings the functions mentioned above can be grouped:

The annual budgets for the listed activities can include the costs of the regional departmental personnel and administrative expenditure, consulting services and work performed by contractors.

The determination of water resource management charges will proceed in the following manner:

 

5.3.2 Funding water resource development and use of waterworks

Water resource development and use of waterworks relate to those activities required to fund the development, operation, maintenance and betterment (improvement) of State water schemes. Water resource development costs and use of waterworks costs are discussed in turn.

Water resource development costs (i.e. capital costs)

In terms of section 56 (2)(b) of the National Water Act, 1998, water resource development costs can include the related costs of investigation, planning, design and construction of water schemes, which constitute the capital cost of projects. The most significant departure from the financing methods used by the DWAF in the past can be found in the treatment of capital costs, which are different from all other costs. This is because long term capital investments, such as water schemes, often have a life which extends beyond a financial year. Three common financial approaches can be used for determining the capital portion of the unit cost of water; they are the "funding" approach, the "depreciation" approach and the "rate of return" approach.

2) Return on Assets Charge

An efficient allocation of scarce capital resources requires that they be priced at the "marginal opportunity cost of capital," or, in other words, the social cost of capital to the country. Since the marginal opportunity cost of capital is a theoretical concept, it will be necessary to approximate this value. A suitable proxy for this, and hence for the desired return on assets, could be:

Real Interest Rate = 5 year moving average treasury rate minus the five year moving average CPI.

The nominal interest rate in any year is set equal to the five year moving average annual treasury rate. Treasury rates are based on the R153 long-term government bond rate (a 15 year bond).

The Department of Finance promotes the use of a five year moving average rather than a fifteen year moving average since this not only reflects the opportunity cost of capital more accurately, but also has a damping effect on interest rate fluctuations.

The return on assets charge will be determined by applying an interest rate (i.e. a percentage) to the current cost (i.e. depreciated replacement value) of water infrastructure assets. It is important to note that the real interest rate discussed above (i.e. the proxy for the marginal opportunity cost of capital) represents a benchmark figure, and the long-term goal for the determination of the return on assets charge. However, application of such a charge in the short- to medium-term is likely to result in tariff increases that are not affordable to the majority of 1st tier water users.

Thus, for this first phase of the pricing strategy, the return on assets charge will be based on a percentage well below the benchmark real interest rate. In line with Department of Finance guidelines in this regard, a real interest rate of four percent will be applied to the depreciated replacement cost of water infrastructure assets to determine the return on assets charge.

3) Smoothing of water resource development charge

It is important to note that the strict application of a constant interest rate to the depreciated replacement value of water infrastructure would give rise to declining costs over time in real terms (i.e. the depreciated replacement value of an asset is lower in year 2 than year 1). This, coupled to growing annual water demands, could produce declining annual water resource development charges for depreciation and return on assets, which would be problematic from a number of perspectives. First, the notion of declining tariffs would run counter to the principle of efficient pricing of scarce resources. And second, declining tariffs would ultimately lead to significant hikes in tariffs when assets reached the end of their useful lives and had to be replaced.

In order to avoid declining tariffs, it will be necessary on a scheme-by-scheme basis to establish water resource development charges which increase gradually initially from current levels, but which are ultimately constant in real terms. Such an "average" tariff would under-recover during the first few year’s of a scheme’s useful life, building up to full cost recovery and the generation of surpluses (to compensate for the under-recovery years) over time. Given that DWAF schemes are at various stages of their useful lives, under-recovery on any particular scheme will be more than offset by recovery on other schemes. Thus, the DWAF will be in a position to finance deficits on specific schemes from its general revenue base.

Treatment of Reserves

When full cost recovery is achieved, the depreciation and return on asset charges will result in a reserve fund being built up over time. As long as government water schemes are owned by the DWAF, these reserve funds will revert to the treasury. DWAF will establish an accounting system to record the extent and use of these funds. If, however, an alternative institutional model is developed in the future and a national public water utility is established, such reserves would be used by the utility to fund its loan commitments and for new investments in water infrastructure.

Assurance of Supply (Section 56 (4)(b)(iii) of the Act)

In determining tariffs of multi-purpose waterworks, it will be necessary to consider the level of assurance at which water is supplied to the various users in order to allocate capital costs between different users. Users that require a higher assurance of supply, for example, would have to pay a premium for their water allocation relative to those users who require a lower assurance of supply. This will be effected in the following way:

Pre-financing (Section 56 (2)(b)(iii) of the Act)

It may be necessary to include pre-financing into the tariffs of existing schemes during the development phase of identified future augmentations, upgrades and expansions. This will ensure a smooth price setting process in the long term and the avoidance of sudden and significant hikes in water prices. It is important to note that pre-financing is not a cost per se, but rather the reallocation of costs over time. Pre-financing will also include the direct financing of the annual costs of planning feasibility studies for augmentation schemes, by means of user charges.

Use of waterworks costs

These are the costs, both direct and indirect, that are incurred in the operating of government water schemes. These are broken down between direct and indirect scheme costs.

1) Direct Scheme Costs

These are the fixed and variable costs which can be attributed directly to administering, operating and maintaining a scheme. Direct costs include administration costs, operations and maintenance costs, pumping costs, direct labour and overheads and distribution costs.

2) Indirect Scheme Costs

These are the costs which cannot be directly attributed to a specific scheme, but which contribute towards the management and operation of the water resources of the entire region, and comprise the DWAF regional office costs, a portion of which can be allocated to individual schemes using an equitable allocation base. Indirect scheme costs will be allocated in proportion to the budgeted direct annual costs of the various schemes and water management areas.

Implementing a charge to fund water resource development and use of waterworks

The DWAF has created three separate trading accounts for:

Water resource development and use of waterworks charges will be implemented as follows:

5.3.3 Achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water

It is important to note that the proposals regarding the funding of water resource management and water resource development and use of waterworks that have been described above will make a significant contribution towards achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water.

However, in the context of increasing water resources scarcity, it may be necessary to introduce additional economic incentives in order to optimise the allocation of scarce water resources between competing uses. Such economic incentives could be introduced in water-stressed areas; the objective being to shift water use from low to high values.

If it is deemed necessary to introduce economic incentives in water-stressed catchments, this can be achieved administratively (via an explicit charge) or via market-orientated mechanisms.

5.4    Transparency and Accountability

It is important to note that in establishing the pricing strategy, every attempt will be made to control costs by the application of sound financial management principles such as strict budgetary control. The new pricing strategy embraces the principle of transparency, which of itself should promote cost control. In terms of this principle, the forthcoming year’s sectoral charges that are developed during the budgetary process for each catchment and scheme will be forwarded to regional offices for dissemination and discussion with interested parties. Final sectoral charges will then be formalised and made available to the regional offices for re-distribution to the area offices, prior to the commencement of the financial year.

In addition, a summarised version of the budgeted trading accounts for the forthcoming year, detailing estimated deficits and surpluses of accounts, will be made available at the regional offices for discussion with the representative bodies of stake-holders, prior to the commencement of the financial year. Similarly, after financial year end, summarised trading accounts reflecting actual expenditure and revenue compared to budget expenditure and revenue for the year, will be made available at the regional offices.

6.    Phasing In The New Approach

6.1    Introduction

The starting point for the phasing in of the new pricing strategy is the recognition that there are fundamental differences between water use charges for a) funding water resource management, b) funding water resource development and use of waterworks, and c) achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water.

It is important to note that while both water resource management and water resource development and use of waterworks charges reflect financial costs, there is a logical difference between the two which requires that they be separated. Water resource development and use of waterworks charges are only levied on the users of specific government water schemes or systems, and are based on the costs associated with that scheme. Water resource management charges, on the other hand, relate to all water utilised within the water management area and should, therefore, be charged to all water users, irrespective of whether water is provided from a government water scheme or not.

Finally, when introduced, a charge for achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water would reflect not a financial cost, but rather an economic one, the objective of which would be to provide incentives for water to be allocated to those who value it highly. Like the water resource management charge, such a charge would be catchment-specific and would apply in water-stressed areas.

It is clear from the above that a fundamental principle underlying the proposed pricing strategy is that eventually it should apply to all water, not just that which is supplied from government water schemes.

6.2 Phasing in the Various Charges

The phasing in of the proposed water pricing strategy will have to be structured so as to follow the phased implementation of the National Water Act, 1998. The process for phasing in can be summarised as follows:

Water Resource Management Charges

The introduction of water resource management charges will have to proceed more slowly than the introduction of water resource development and use of waterworks charges (see below), as the registration of all water use in water management areas is a pre-requisite for its full implementation. The current situation is that charges relating to the water resource management functions of water conservation (invasive plant and water weeds removal) and water utilisation (abstraction, storage and afforestation permit control) have already been introduced for water users at Government water schemes. Registration will be prioritised in the catchments of those schemes so that all water users can be charged in an equitable way.

Water Resource Development and Use of Waterworks Charges

The phasing in of full cost recovery for water sold from government schemes can be introduced more rapidly, as the users thereof are easily identifiable. This will have to be done bearing in mind standing agreements with specific user groups and affordability constraints (See section 7 below).

Charges for Achieving the Equitable and Efficient Allocation of Water

As already mentioned above, proposals regarding the funding of water resource management and water resource development and use of waterworks will make a significant contribution towards achieving the equitable and efficient allocation of water. Thus, the introduction of additional economic incentives will not feature in this first phase of the pricing strategy. The reason for this is that it is acknowledged that it would be premature to introduce economic pricing at this early stage. Pricing on the basis of economic principles can only reasonably be considered once the effect of full financial costing of water on resource utilisation has been evaluated.

Were economic incentives to be introduced in the future, they would initially involve fairly substantial reliance on administrative price setting subject to political supervision. The reasons for this are that:

 

7.  Application Of Pricing Strategy To Different Categories Of Water Use / User Sectors

Section 56 of the National Water Act, 1998 also provides for the pricing strategy to differentiate on an equitable basis between-

This differentiation is discussed with regard to the main categories of water use / water users in detail below.

7.1 Discharge of Waste (Section 56(5) of the Act)

Discharging of waste or water containing waste into a water resource is also defined as a water use for which charges can be imposed. It is the Department’s intention to develop and implement a waste discharge pricing system which will be based on the "polluter pays principle" (PPP) to provide economic incentives to reduce water pollution to the level with the least cost to society as a whole.

The waste discharge pricing strategy will form part of the introduction of economic charges in terms of section 56 (2)(c) of the Act and will be separate from the water resource management charge in respect of water quality management.

A separate project will be initiated in 1999 to develop the pricing strategy for waste discharges. It will include the determination of future charges for point and diffuse sources of pollution, based on the "polluter pays principle". This will include measures to internalise the cost of water pollution, as well as economic incentives and disincentives to promote the reduction of waste discharge. The pricing strategy in this regard will be developed and published for public comment in due course.

7.2 Municipal Sector

1.  Water resource management charge: The current method of determining catchment management charges for water supplied from Government water schemes -- relating to the estimated proportional activity costs of water conservation (invasive plants and water weeds removal) and water utilisation (abstraction, storage and afforestation permit control) -- is consistent with the new strategy and will be continued. However, adaptations will be made after the registration of all water users in the particular catchments has been accomplished and more accurate data on sectoral water use becomes available.

Charges for the full recovery of the other allocated water resource management costs will only be introduced once all the water users in the particular catchment in which the scheme is located have been registered. Water resource management charges for the municipal sector will also reflect the fact that only the "economic" uses of water from the catchment, scheme or system will contribute towards cost recovery (i.e. excluding basic human needs).

2. Water resource development and use of waterworks charge: This charge will be based on full financial cost recovery. The determination of unit costs for water supplied from Government water schemes, based on the notional loan approach, will be replaced by determining the unit costs through the proposed new approach as set out in this strategy. The principle of excluding the water requirements for basic human needs for purposes of setting 1st tier prices will be introduced.

3. Phasing in of charges: A maximum increase of 20% over current tariffs for the first number of years of the new pricing strategy will be implemented. The objective is to achieve full cost recovery within ten years. Thereafter, tariffs are expected to increase annually with the inflation rate.

7.3  Industrial and Mining Sector

The application of the first tier pricing strategy to this sector will be identical to that of the municipal sector, except for the aspect of dealing with basic human needs. It will be based on full financial cost recovery by charging for "economic" uses of water in the catchment and the phasing in of new charges. A maximum increase of 20% over current tariffs for the first number of years of the new pricing strategy will be implemented. The objective is to achieve full cost recovery within ten years. Thereafter, annual increases will be limited to the inflation rate.

7.4  Irrigation Sector

Established schemes and commercial farmers

1. Water resource management charge: Full recovery of water resource management costs must be achieved in a phased approach. The agreement reached with the South African Agricultural Union (SAAU) makes provision for the allocated costs for the Working for Water Programme (water conservation) to be subsidised by 90% due to the fact that this activity will only increase the assurance of supply to this sector and will not make additional supplies available. The water resource management activity costs relating to water conservation (invasive plant and water weed control) and water utilisation (storage, abstraction and afforestation permit control) which have already been introduced, plus a 10% surcharge (to account for under-recovery of costs during drought years), will be phased in together with operation and maintenance costs, to be recovered in full by the year 2001. Thereafter the other water resource management costs will also be introduced for water pricing purposes, but only after all the water uses in a particular water management area have been registered and a new agreement has been negotiated.

2.   Water resource development and use of waterworks charge: In line with an agreement between the DWAF and the SAAU, all management, operating, maintenance and current refurbishment costs, together with certain water resource management costs plus a 10% surcharge, will be recovered in respect of existing Government schemes by the year 2001, by gradually phasing out the subsidy over a five year period. The agreement also makes provision for the full recovery of future refurbishment and betterment costs. This agreement will be reviewed in 2001, during which time a contribution to the allocated capital costs of existing schemes, in line with the pricing strategy, may be considered. The new pricing strategy also makes provision for full financial cost recovery for any new schemes to be developed by the Department.

3. Phasing in of charges: Total existing tariffs will be increased gradually to reach full recovery of the SAAU negotiated costs in the year 2001. The maximum annual increase of existing tariffs will be limited to 50% of the previous tariff during this period. Tariffs would also not be decreased in any year. Beyond the year 2001, the other water resource management activity unit costs for water resource management and a possible contribution towards water resource development costs will be added to the charge. Terms of a new agreement will be negotiated.

Water User Associations (Irrigation Board Schemes)

In the case of waterworks built by Water User Associations, each Association will be responsible to redeem the loan commitments within the agreed redemption period. For this purpose charges may be levied on a proportional or differential basis, depending on the provisions of an association’s constitution.

Ex-homeland schemes and emerging irrigation farmers

In redressing the imbalances with respect to irrigation farming in the past, it should be noted that the State is committed to supporting disadvantaged individuals and communities through land restitution, land reform, or other programmes of corrective action. These could include concessionary periods during which the full cost of water, based on the approach proposed in this document, is not levied. The concessionary period in which the full cost of water is not levied would be considered on an ad hoc basis as a form of establishment support in the case of newly established farming or similar enterprises. A minimum phasing-in period of 5 years for water resource management plus the use of waterwork charges on State canal irrigation schemes is proposed, in order to bring the strategy in line with current practice on established schemes.

Stepped water tariffs

To promote water conservation and the beneficial use of water in terms of the National Water Act, the introduction of stepped water tariffs for irrigation will form part of the pricing strategy. The present agreement with the SAAU regarding the phasing-in of the recovery of current expenditure at schemes may lead to under-recovery of costs if stepped tariffs are introduced immediately, and such an immediate introduction may therefore be counterproductive. The introduction of stepped tariff structures also needs further applied research and refinement and can furthermore only be effectively applied where water supply is accurately measured and monitored.

To initiate the process of introducing demand management in irrigation, it is proposed that a two-part pricing system be introduced on established State schemes. For the first round of the pricing strategy, the price should consist of a basic payment regardless of actual use, equivalent to 90% of the required rate per hectare determined in terms of the SAAU agreement, plus an equivalent rate per cubic meter for actual volumes consumed above 90% of the quota. The full implementation of the stepped tariff structures for irrigation will then be introduced with the revision of the SAAU agreement in the year 2001.

Government institutions

Water supplied for irrigation purposes from State schemes to other government departments or institutions financially supported by government departments, will be charged a tariff based on full financial cost recovery, without subsidisation.

Purchase of "extra water"

The current policy of allowing scheduled irrigators on Government water schemes to purchase "extra water" under certain conditions at heavily subsidised prices will be discontinued. Only under exceptional circumstances, such as an unexpected heat wave, will irrigators be allowed to purchase additional water over and above the quotas. The tariff for such extra water will be the raw water tariff for domestic and industrial supply.

7.5  Streamflow Reduction Activities

Water resource management charge: Full recovery of allocated water resource management costs, based on the total registered average annual volumetric water use, must be achieved. The National Water Act makes provision for the DWAF to make regulations for making a volumetric determination of water to be ascribed to a stream flow reduction activity for purposes of water use allocation and the imposition of charges. The necessary regulations (which involves a public participation process) and registration of existing lawful water use will precede the imposition of charges in any water management area.

In terms of the National Water Act, 1998, forestry is declared as a streamflow reduction activity. Existing and new forestry plantations will attract charges for water resource management, while prospective permit holders could be allowed to tender for allocations during a public auction process. Charges will be converted to a rate per hectare and will differ from catchment to catchment.

7.6  Non-consumptive Use of Water

Generation of hydro-electric power

Charges for making use of State water works for generating electricity will be based on the current unit cost of burning coal for Eskom coal-fired power stations, expressed in cents per kilowatt-hour, plus a 10% surcharge. Where Eskom is a party to a joint hydro-electric venture with the DWAF, an agreement on water use charges must be negotiated.

Rebate for water returned to a resource

Although section 56 (3)(d) of the National Water Act states that the pricing strategy may provide for a rebate on water returned to a water resource, the initial pricing strategy does not cover this aspect. This must be considered with due cognisance of the development of the pricing strategy for waste discharge charges.

Dewatering of mines

Underground water removed for mining purposes and discharged into a water resource as directed by the DWAF will not be subject to pricing for the quantity of water removed, but waste discharge charges may be applicable in terms of the new pricing strategy to be developed for waste discharges.

Water for recreational purposes

Charges for water stored for recreational purposes will be directed towards the volumetric use for the initial filling of the impoundment and the estimated annual evaporation from the dam surface.

7.7 Licensing and Registration Fees

The determination of fees payable in terms of the National Water Act with regard to applications for new licenses (Section 40 (3)) will be based on the estimated unit cost of processing a license application. Fees will be determined annually by the responsible authority for a particular water management area. For purposes of the initial pricing strategy, a uniform national application fee will be announced for each financial year. These fees will be waived in case of individual license applications of members of previously disadvantaged groups in rural areas.

The payment of fees for the registration of existing lawful water uses as requested by the DWAF will be waived in respect of all water users for purposes of the initial pricing strategy.

8.     Conclusion

This document has presented a resource pricing approach for South African water, based on financial and economic principles, and taking into account the country’s social and ecological objectives. It has argued that supply-side approaches to address the problem of water scarcity are all but exhausted, and that an integrated approach, containing also demand-side measures represent the only viable long-run solution to the management of South Africa’s water resources.

The new approach to water pricing recognises this, and proposes that the full financial cost of 1st tier water eventually be recovered from water users. Where necessary, this financial charge may ultimately be supplemented by an economic charge in water-scarce catchments, in order to reflect the relative scarcity of water as a commodity at a given time and place and thus to promote the efficient allocation and beneficial use of water.

Finally, it would be premature to assign definite time-frames to the staged phasing-in of full economic pricing in the absence of actual data. However, it is important to remember that the country’s scarce water resources are at great risk if the move towards economic pricing is delayed any longer than is absolutely necessary.

Glossary Of Terms

Social equity: In the context of water resources, social equity implies that all user groups have fair and reasonable access to the nation’s scarce water resources, and that the allocation of water resources facilitates universal and affordable access to a basic water supply.

Ecological sustainability: This concept captures the view that there is a need to treat ecological protection and continuing economic growth as mutually compatible rather than as necessarily conflicting objectives.

Economic efficiency: A condition that is achieved when resources are used over a given period of time in such a way as to make it impossible to increase the welfare of any person without harming another.

Economic value: The cost that represents the scarcity value of a good which would prevail in competitive markets.

Economics: Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.

Externalities: are essentially activities whose full cost or benefit is not incorporated into an economic decision; hence they lead to sub-optimal social allocation.

Market approach: This is an accepted means through which buyers and sellers can communicate and trade at mutually agreed terms.

Market clearance: A condition that is attained when the price of the good traded adjusts so that the quantity buyers wish to buy is equal to the quantity which sellers wish to supply.

Opportunity costs: The costs of alternatives forgone by using scarce resources in a particular manner.

Polluter pays principle: A principle that ensures that a charge per unit of pollution emitted into the ecosystem is charged to those responsible for such pollution in order to internalise the cost thereof.

Scarcity: The situation which arises when demand for any given good outstrips the supply of that good.

Water market: A market where water is traded in the same fashion as other goods.